Economy

How WWII Reduced US Productivity

9 Mins Read

There’s a conventional story that World War II was a uplift for the US economy, both providing a splash of volume demand that ended the Unconfined Depression, and moreover establishing the understructure for several decades of postwar prosperity in US manufacturing. Alexander J. Field begs to differ. He lays out his specimen in “The ripen of US manufacturing productivity between 1941 and 1948” (Economic History Review, published online January 16, 2023).

Of course, total manufacturing output did rises substantially during World War II, but “productivity” for economists doesn’t refer to total output. Instead, productivity refers to output per hour worked–or increasingly generally, output relative to given inputs of labor and capital. With that in mind, you can get some of the savor of the larger perspective of Field’s treatise by taking a squint at this data on the US manufacturing sector form 1929 to 1948. As you see, everything is expressed relative to 1929: that is, the level of all the variables is set at 100 for 1929. The first post is labor productivity, or output per hour. The second is “total factor productivity,” a increasingly ramified (although by no ways truly difficult) numbering that is output per combined inputs of labor and capital. The third post is total manufacturing output; the fourth columns is hours worked in the manufacturing sector, and the last post is stocks of wanted in the manufacturing sector.

 

Before looking at the World War II years, just run your vision over the 1930s for a moment to get a sense of how this works–and perhaps to reset your perceptions of what happened during this time. Manufacturing output falls by half during the Unconfined Depression from 1929 to 1933. The stock of wanted equipment doesn’t fall by much during this time: without all the equipment may have been less used or unused, and some of it would wear out, but the equipment itself was mostly still there. Hours worked in manufacturing falls 40% from 1929 to 1933, which is less than the fall in output. Thus, output per hour worked, as shown in the first post falls substantially from 1929 to 1933.

There is a worldwide perception that the Unconfined Depression lasted throughout the 1930s, surpassing the economy was jolted out of the Depression by World War II spending. The table shows that this perception is untrue. Manufacturing output doubles from 1933 to 1937. The economy is then jolted by a sharp increase in interest rates by the Federal Reserve leading to a steep recession in 1937-38–and then followed by a doubling of manufacturing output from 1938-1941. Readers will remember that while there is certainly fear of war in the late 1930s and early 1940s, the bombing of Pearl Harbor and the very entry of the US into World War II doesn’t happen until Decemer 1941.

As the US scrambled to reshape its economy to a wartime footing, output rises substantially. But there are moreover substantial jumps in labor and wanted inputs. Thus, both labor productivity (output per hour worked of labor) and total factor productivity (output per unit of inputs including labor and capital) start to decline. Field described the underlying process this way:

The [productivity] declines in 1942 reflect, whilom all else, the upturned conditions associated with the changes in the product mix. Productivity took a huge hit as machinery to produce peacetime products made way for newly designed machine tools, and labour and management struggled to wilt proficient as they moved from making goods in which they had a unconfined deal of wits to those in which they had little. Shortages, hoarding of inputs, and production intermittency plagued the war effort. The positive effects of learning by doing are evident in the transpiration in both labour productivity and TFP growth between 1942 and 1943. They were nevertheless insufficient to recoup for the sharp waif during the previous year. Productivity resumed an velocious ripen in 1944, as a secondary round of major product changes kicked in, and was plane increasingly negative in 1945, due in part to the disruptions associated with demobilization. Partial recovery between 1945 and 1948 still left the TFP level in US manufacturing substantially unelevated where it had been in 1941.

There is a conventional narrative well-nigh World War II that it was at least “good for the economy,” but that seems imprecisely put. It’s true that the US economy, with its upper level of technical skills and no-go flexibility, was very good indeed for winning the war–which was unmistakably the highest priority at that time. But the war led to multiple dramatic disruptions in the US economy: restructuring to wartime production in multiple ways and times, labor shortages, supply shortages, and then a dramatic restructuring when to a peacetime economy.

Field offers a reminder that much of the wanted investment made during World War II was useless at the end of the war.

With the temporary exception of B-29 bombers, most of the watercraft produced during the war were, at its conclusion, deemed surplus: obsolete or unneeded. Tens of thousands were flown to boneyards in Arizona: air bases such as Kingman and Davis-Monthan. … Some watercraft were flown directly from the factory gate to Arizona for disassembly and recycling. Many watercraft operating overseas were never repatriated. It was simply not worth the forfeit in fuel and manpower to fly them when to the United States so they could be scrapped. Similar fates befell Liberty ships (scrapped and recycled for the steel), tanks, and other military equipment including field artillery. …

There was indeed a huge investment in plant and equipment by the federal government. But the mass production techniques that made volume production of tanks and watercraft possible in the United States relied overwhelmingly on single- or special-purpose machine tools, and most of these tools and related jigs and frames were scrapped with reconversion. The United States did use multipurpose machine tools, which could increasingly hands be repurposed, but this was principally in the shops producing machine tools. Already in 1944, the country confronted serious
surplus and scrappage issues. By early 1945 disposal agencies had surplus inventories of roughly $2 billion – equivalent to the unshortened forfeit of the Manhattan Project. By V-J Day that had risen to US $4 billion, and ultimately to a peak of US $14.4 billion in mid-1946. …

Both public and private wanted unifying in areas not militarily prioritized had been
repressed.Wartime priorities starved the economy of government investment in streets and highways,
bridges and tunnels, water and sewage systems, hydro power, and other infrastructure that
had played such an important role in the growth of productivity and potential output wideness the
Depression years. These categories of government wanted complementary to private wanted grew
at a combined rate of 0.15 per cent per year between 1941 and 1948, as opposed to 4.17 per cent per
year between 1929 and 1941.81
Portions of the private economy not deemed hair-trigger to the war effort moreover subsisted on a thin
gruel of new physical capital. Trade, transportation, and manufacturing not directly related to the
war are cases in point. Private nonfarm housing starts,which had recovered to 619 500 in 1941, still
34 per cent unelevated the 1925 peak (937 000), plunged to 138 700 in 1944, barely whilom the 1933 trough
of 93 000. All ‘nonessential’ construction in the country was restricted whence on 9 October
1941, scrutinizingly two months surpassing the Japanese attack.82

 

 

Of course, the US economy suffered a terrible loss of workers as a result of World War II. “As for labour, the firsthand post-war impact of the war on potential hours was unmistakably negative: 407 000 mostly prime-age males never returned. Most would have been working in the sparsity of the war. …There were flipside 607 000 military casualties. The 50 per cent wartime rise in sexuality labour-force participation largely prodigal during the immediate
post-war period.

What well-nigh new technologies ripened during World War II? As Field points out, the worthiness to run no-go turnout lines for making planes and ships was not a useful technology without the war ended. Increasingly broadly, he argues that World War II was increasingly well-nigh taking wholesomeness of technologies that had been ripened earlier, not well-nigh the invention of technologies that would have lasting benefits in peacetime.

What of increasingly unstipulated scientific and technological advance? Kelly, Papanikolaou, Seru, and Taddy digitized scrutinizingly the unshortened corpus of US patent filings between 1840 and 2010, and analysing word counts, identified transilience patents: those that were novel at the time and influential afterwards. Such patents had low wrong-side-up similarity and upper forward similarity scores … Their time series of such patents shows a peak in the 1930s, particularly the first half of the decade, and a noticeable trough during the war years …

Much of what occurred during the war represented the exploitation of a preexisting knowledge base. In 1945, Vannevar Bush published Science, the uncounted frontier, a work often viewed as distilling the lessons and achievements of the war into an violating tabulation for post-war science and technology policy. However, as David Mowery noted, ‘the Bush report unceasingly took the position that the remarkable technological achievements of World War II represented a depletion of the reservoir of vital scientific knowledge’ ,,,

It is of undertow untellable to re-run history and see what would have happened if the economic trends of the late 1930s had unfurled without the interruptions, costs, and material and human losses of World War II. But it is surely possible that the US have had a stronger economy in 1950 if it had not suffered losses of a million killed and wounded, and had not needed to scramble its outputs first to a wartime and then to a peacetime footing, and had been worldly-wise to pursue non-war science and technology. Field goes so far as to speculate: “From a long-run perspective, the war can be seen, ironically, as the whence of the end of US world economic dominance in
manufacturing.”

Given this kind of evidence, why is the weighing in the economic benefits of World War II so tightly rooted? Field quote Elizabeth Samet’s treatise that there is “pernicious American sentimentality well-nigh nation” and that “we search for a redemptive ending to every tragedy.” There is surely some truth in this, but perhaps a simpler truth is that the losses and financing of World War II are too staggering to contemplate.

 

The post How WWII Reduced US Productivity first appeared on Conversable Economist.

X